Social norms and the fertility transition

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.01.002Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper provides a norm-based explanation for two features of the fertility transition that have been observed in many different settings: the slow response to external interventions and the wide variation in the response to the same intervention. Most societies have traditionally put norms into place to regulate fertility. When the economic environment changes, individuals gradually learn through their social interactions about the new reproductive equilibrium that will emerge in their community. This characterization of the fertility transition as a process of changing social norms is applied to rural Bangladesh, where norms are organized at the level of the religious group and interactions rarely cross religious boundaries. Consistent with the view that changing social norms are driving changes in reproductive behavior in these communities, we find that the individual's contraception decision responds strongly to changes in contraceptive prevalence in her own religious group within the village whereas cross-religion effects are entirely absent. Local changes in reproductive behavior occur independently across religious groups despite the fact that all individuals in the village have access to the same family planning inputs.

Introduction

Countries at similar levels of economic development are often seen to display very different patterns of fertility behavior (Bongaarts and Watkins, 1996). Although fertility rates have declined throughout the world over the past decades, long delays and wide differentials in the response to family planning programs have also been frequently observed, both across countries as well as within countries (see, for instance, Bulatao, 1998; Cleland et al., 1994; NRC, 1993). One explanation for these stylized facts is based on the idea that many aspects of individual behavior, including fertility, are socially regulated in a traditional economy. While such social regulation has advantages of its own, the drawback is that it may prevent individuals from responding immediately to new economic opportunities. Social norms are typically seen to emerge in environments characterized by multiple equilibria, to keep the community in a preferred equilibrium (Kandori, 1992). Changes in the economic environment, such as the availability of modern contraceptives, could reopen the possibility for such multiple equilibria, which would explain the slow response to external interventions, as well as the differential response to the same external stimulus, as each community gradually converges to a new reproductive equilibrium.1

The setting for this study is the fertility transition in rural Bangladesh. The International Centre for Diarrhoeal Disease Research, Bangladesh (ICDDR,B) launched a Maternal Child Health–Family Planning (MCH-FP) project in 1978, covering seventy villages in Matlab thana, Comilla district. The MCH-FP project is quite possibly the most intensive family planning program ever put in place: all households in the intervention area have been visited by a Community Health Worker (CHW) once every 2 weeks since the inception of the project in 1978, and contraceptives are provided to them free of cost. Despite these economic incentives, and the sustained pressure on the households to change their behavior, we still see long delays in the adoption of contraceptives. The family planning program was already well established in the intervention area by the time our data began in 1983. Nevertheless, contraception levels continued to increase steadily over the sample period (1983–93), from 40% in 1983 to 63% in 1993, with an accompanying decline in total fertility rates from 4.5 children per woman to 2.9 children over that period. Wide variation in long-run contraceptive prevalence is also observed across villages in the intervention area.

Most societies have traditionally put norms into place to regulate fertility. In rural Bangladesh, the traditional norm was characterized by early and universal marriage, followed by immediate and continuous child-bearing. Religious authority provided legitimacy and enforced the rules that sustained this equilibrium. In such a social environment, the unexpected availability of modern contraceptives through the family planning program would have opened up the possibility for new equilibria, in which a sufficient fraction of the women in the village ignored the religious sanctions and began to regulate fertility. The point of departure for our simple model of fertility change, following the exogenous economic intervention, is a social uncertainty: the individual does not know what level of contraceptive prevalence will ultimately be sustained in her community. This uncertainty is slowly resolved over time as women in the village interact sequentially with each other from one period to the next, which explains the gradual change in contraceptive prevalence that we see in the data, as well as the convergence to different levels of contraceptive use across communities.

While this characterization of social change as a learning process explains the broad stylized facts that we described above, it also allows us to endogenously derive the individual's decision rule during the transition from the traditional equilibrium to the modern equilibrium: The contraception decision in any time period is determined by the individual's lagged decision and the lagged level of contraceptive prevalence in the community. However, this prediction by itself has little bite since it is well known that a spurious correlation between the individual's decision and her neighbors' past decisions could be obtained when unobserved determinants of the contraception decision are correlated across neighbors and over time (Manski, 1993). For example, neighbors' decisions could simply proxy for changes in economic opportunities or the effectiveness of the MCH-FP project itself.

Our strategy in this paper to provide additional support for the view that changes in contraceptive prevalence were driven by changes in underlying social norms takes advantage of the institutional background that we will provide in Section 2. Female mobility in Bangladesh has traditionally been severely restricted by the institution of purdah. Young married women will rarely leave the homestead (bari), and when they do, it will typically be to visit extended family or kin. While the two major religious groups in rural Bangladesh, Hindus (who constitute 18% of the population in our villages) and Muslims, share a common language and a common Bengali culture, female interactions almost never cross religious boundaries even within the village. Changes in social norms must thus occur independently across religious groups within the village.

We test these implications of the model with a unique data set, which includes contraceptive use information as well as demographic and socioeconomic characteristics for all the women residing in the 70 villages in the intervention area over an 11-year period (1983–93). Consistent with the preceding prediction, we present the striking result in Section 5 that while individuals respond strongly to contraceptive prevalence within their own religious group in the village, cross-religion effects are entirely absent in the data. In contrast, when we partition the village by other variables, such as age or education, we consistently observe large and significant cross-group effects. We will also show in Section 5 that omitted determinants of the individual's contraceptive decision must be completely uncorrelated across religious groups within the village to spuriously generate the within-religion and cross-religion patterns that we just described. We will argue in that section that standard omitted variables, such as unobserved program effects or economic change, which complicated the interpretation of the estimated contraception decision rule above, are unlikely to satisfy this condition. For example, while health inputs and information signals supplied by the MCH-FP project may have varied across religious groups within the village, it is difficult to imagine that they were uncorrelated across these groups. After all, it is the same agency, and the same CHW, that is providing these inputs.2

The paper is organized in six sections. Section 2 describes the institutional setting, paying special attention to the social restrictions that prevented the immediate adoption of contraceptives in the intervention area. Section 3 describes the village level data: we see a gradual change in contraceptive prevalence over time as well as sorting across villages to different long-run contraceptive prevalence levels. Section 4 presents a simple model of social change that is consistent with these stylized facts. The individual's (optimal) decision rule is also derived in this section. Section 5 subsequently presents the data and the estimation results that support the view that religion-specific social interactions gave rise to the changes in reproductive behavior that we see in the data. Section 6 concludes the paper.

Section snippets

The institutional setting

Our primary objective in this section is to describe the social restrictions that prevented the rapid spread of contraception in the intervention area. By making modern contraceptives available for the first time, the MCH-FP project ran counter to the practice of early and universal marriage followed by immediate and continuous child-bearing, followed traditionally throughout rural Bangladesh (Arthur and McNicoll, 1978). Not surprisingly, the MCH-FP project faced strong opposition from

Aggregate patterns in the data

We now describe two important features of the data, which will motivate the model of social change that we present later in Section 4: the gradual increase in contraceptive prevalence over time and the sorting among the villages to different long-run levels of contraceptive prevalence.

We begin by describing the gradual change in contraceptive use over time. Contraceptive use information for all eligible women, 15–49 years, married and capable of conceiving, is available at two points in each

A simple model of social change

Our first objective in this section is to present a model of decentralized social change that can explain the two stylized facts that we described above. The point of departure for the model is a social uncertainty following the introduction of the family planning program: the individual does not know the reproductive equilibrium that her community will ultimately converge to. We will see that this uncertainty is gradually resolved as individuals interact sequentially with each other over time.

Individual level empirical analysis

This section begins with a brief description of the data in Section 5.1. Subsequently we discuss the identification problem in Section 5.2. A spurious relationship between the individual's contraception decision and neighbors' lagged decisions could be obtained if unobserved determinants of contraceptive use are correlated within the village. However, our characterization of the fertility transition as a process of changing social norms implies that the relevant social interactions should be

Conclusion

This paper provides a norm-based explanation for two features of the fertility transition that have been observed in many different settings: The slow response to external interventions and the wide variation in the response to the same intervention. Most societies have traditionally put norms into place to regulate fertility. When new opportunities become available, individuals gradually learn through their social interactions about the specific reproductive equilibrium that will emerge in

Acknowledgements

We thank Dan Ackerberg, Orazio Attanasio, Abhijit Banerjee, Sam Bowles, Joytsnamoy Chakraborty, Esther Duflo, Stephen Donald, Jan Eeckhout, Andrew Foster, Jeroen van Ginniken, Michael Kremer, Kevin Lang, Nancy Luke, Dilip Mookherjee, Jack Porter, Andrew Postlewaite, Mark Rosenzweig, Frank Schorfheide, T. Paul Schultz, Frank Vella, Peyton Young, numerous seminar participants and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments. We are especially grateful to George Mailath for many helpful

References (36)

  • Sajeda Amin

    The poverty-purdah trap in rural Bangladesh: implications for women's roles in the family

    Development and Change

    (1997)
  • Sajeda Amin et al.

    Contraception and religiosity in Bangladesh

  • Brian W. Arthur et al.

    An analytical survey of population and development in Bangladesh

    Population and Development Review

    (1978)
  • Abhijit V. Banerjee

    A simple model of herd behavior

    The Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1992)
  • Abhijit V. Banerjee

    The economics of rumours

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1993)
  • Sushil Bikhchandani et al.

    A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1992)
  • John Bongaarts et al.

    Social interactions and contemporary fertility transitions

    Population and Development Review

    (1996)
  • Rodolfo Bulatao

    The Value of Family Planning Programs in Developing Countries

    (1998)
  • Cain et al.

    Class, Patriarchy and Women's Work in Bangladesh

    Population and Development Review

    (1979)
  • John Cleland et al.

    The Determinants of Reproductive Change in Bangladesh

    (1994)
  • Glenn Ellison

    Cooperation in the prisoner's dilemma with anonymous random matching

    The Review of Economic Studies

    (1994)
  • Ilan Eshel et al.

    Altruists, egoists, and hooligans in a local interaction model

    American Economic Review

    (1998)
  • V. Fauveau et al.

    Epidemiology and cause of deaths among women in rural Bangladesh

    International Journal of Epidemiology

    (1989)
  • E. Glaeser et al.

    Crime and social interactions

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1996)
  • Cheng Hsiao

    Analysis of panel data

    (1986)
  • Michihiro Kandori

    Social norms and community enforcement

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1992)
  • M.A. Koenig et al.

    Maternal mortality in Matlab, Bangladesh: 1976–85

    Studies in Family Planning

    (1988)
  • G.S. Maddala

    Limited dependent variable models using panel data

    Journal of Human Resources

    (1987)
  • Cited by (176)

    • Learning in networks with idiosyncratic agents

      2024, Games and Economic Behavior
    • Women's education and fertility in China

      2023, China Economic Review
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text